The Paradox of Thrift

Definition

  • According to the paradox of thrift, efforts to save more might be self-defeating and in fact lead to less saving and investment.

  • In neoclassical economics, saving can sometimes be “too high” (dynamic inefficiency); however by assumption more saving always translates into more investment.

  • According to one version of Keynesian economics, this is not correct: investment does not depend much on the cost of capital.

  • This could be due to the fact that the growth rate \(g\) is a lower bound for \(r\) (capitalists never want a lower return than that; if returns get lower, they just stop investing)

Keynes (1936) - Chapter 7

This phenomenon was explained by J.M. Keynes in Chapter 7 - “The Meaning of Saving and Investment Further Considered” of the General Theory:

Keynes (1936) - Chapter 24

  • Keynes restates the paradox of thrift in Chapter 24 “Concluding Notes on the Social Philosophy Towards which the General Theory Might Lead.”

  • In this chapter, Keynes argues that a higher saving rate (lower propensity to consume) need not increase capital accumulation. On the contrary, it might lower it:

Chapter 24: the vanishing importance of thrift

Counterintuitive? Immoral?

  • Idea that thrift is always virtuous is very deeply ingrained in our culture.

  • It is a matter of philosophy, morals, and sometimes even religion. (e.g. the “protestant ethic”)

  • For example, in the Walt Disney movie Mary Poppins, Michael is being lectured by a banker that he should not be “feeding the birds” (=spend) but instead invest his tuppence “wisely in the bank” to “be part of railways through Africa; Dams across the Nile, fleets of ocean Greyhounds; Majestic, self-amortizing canals; Plantations of ripening tea” (save and invest).

  • Interestingly, these capital investments are all abroad; we shall come back to this later.

Walt Disney movie Mary Poppins

Paradox of thrift by Samuelson (1948)

Counterintuitive? Immoral? - Samuelson (1948)

Neoclassical VS Keynesian regimes

Benjamin Franklin

Before J.M. Keynes

Very early

The paradox of thrift was known before J.M. Keynes, perhaps in the Book of Proverbs:

There is that scattereth, and yet increaseth; and there is that withholdeth more than is meet, but it tendeth to poverty. (Proverbs 11:24)

More certainly, it was present as early as in Bernard Mandeville’s The Fable of the Bees: or, Private Vices, Public Benefits (1714):

As this prudent economy, which some people call Saving, is in private families the most certain method to increase an estate, so some imagine that, whether a country be barren or fruitful, the same method if generally pursued (which they think practicable) will have the same effect upon a whole nation, and that, for example, the English might be much richer than they are, if they would be as frugal as some of their neighbours. This, I think, is an error.

Bernard Mandeville’s Fable of the Bees (1714)

Bernard Mandeville’s Fable of the Bees (1714)

Malthus (1820) - Principles of Political Economy

Malthus (1820) - Principles of Political Economy

Malthus (1820) - Principles of Political Economy

Crocker and Macvane (1887) - General overproduction

Hobson

Austerity leads to a fall in investment

Crowding in, Paradox of thrift

  • A rise in public saving, according to neoclassical economics, should boost investment.

Alesina, Favero, and Giavazzi (2019)

  • Alesina, Favero, Giavazzi now agree that tax-based austerity generates a long-run fall in investment. Note:

  • Also pervasive: same using Romer and Romer (2010)’s narrative fiscal shocks.

  • More generally: consumption, investment and output are positively correlated even conditional on aggregate demand shocks.

Alesina, Favero, and Giavazzi (2019)

Romer and Romer (2010): Investment

Romer and Romer (2010): Saving

Riera-Crichton, Vegh, and Vuletin (2016) - Investment

Riera-Crichton, Vegh, and Vuletin (2016) - Saving

World Economic Outlook 2015 (IMF)

Krugman

Krugman

Ricardian equivalence or the paradox of thrift

Bibliography

Alesina, Alberto, Carlo Favero, and Francesco Giavazzi. 2019. Austerity: When It Works and When It Doesn’t. Princeton University Press.
Crocker, Uriel H., and S. M. Macvane. 1887. “General Overproduction.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 1 (3): 362–66. https://doi.org/10.2307/1882763.
Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money.
Riera-Crichton, Daniel, Carlos A. Vegh, and Guillermo Vuletin. 2016. “Tax Multipliers : Pitfalls in Measurement and Identification.” Journal of Monetary Economics 79: 30–48. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2016.03.003.
Romer, Christina D., and David H. Romer. 2010. “The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: Estimates Based on a New Measure of Fiscal Shocks.” American Economic Review 100 (3): 763–801. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.3.763.
Samuelson, Paul A. 1948. Economics. New York Toronto London: McGraw-Hill Book Company.